And back then, as now,
the protectionists were people who wanted to promote a diverse industrial base.
Protection was also seen as crucial to the well-being of the working class. The
great Liberal Alfred Deakin declared in 1901 that "if federal protection
increases the manufacturers' profits, state laws must provide that the employee
shall secure his share, perhaps by means of special boards for wages and hours,
according to the plan partly adopted by Victoria". (Robert Birrell,
"A Nation of Our Own", p. 170.)
A similar insight into
why the protectionists did not support free trade comes from the Bulletin's
leader writer, James Edmond, in his 1900 tract "A Policy for the
Commonwealth". He says "No country ever became a great industrial
state under free trade unless it had cheaper labour than its neighbours, and
cheap labour means degradation and slavery... Nor can any nation, in these days
of cheap freights, remain a great industrial state under free trade unless it
pays as low wages as the cheapest of its rivals, or unless its workers can hold
their own by exceptional skill". (Ibid). Observers watching the way in
which nowadays the rich get richer while low paid workers are becalmed or going
backwards might think Mr. Edmond just as relevant today.
The view of many
protectionists and particularly the social democrats among them was that
Australia should learn from the mistakes of the 'old world' and become a 'new
world’, free of both the social divisions and strong class boundaries of the
United Kingdom, and the slavery which had blighted the United States. We were to do our own dirty work rather than
expect someone else to do it. Australia was not to be like America, where
competition reigned supreme at the expense of workers' long-term will-being.
This outlook was egalitarian, and helped give the Australia of the Federation
era a democratic culture – that Jack is as good as his master, and down with
"tall poppies", or at least those who give themselves airs. (Ibid, p.
281).
Bob Birrell concludes
that the Federation era and the 'Australian Settlement' offers ideals directly
relevant to our present dilemmas, and that it is a shame that it has been
disparaged by Australia's cultural gatekeepers. (Ibid, p. 283).
It has been fashionable
for years to deride the Australian economic, political institutions and culture
of the Federation era, often referred to as the Australian Settlement. And the
Settlement itself was effectively torn up several decades ago.
But I believe many of
the things done at that time served Australia well and indeed are key reasons
why we developed a more egalitarian, more prosperous, fairer society than many
other countries were able to accomplish. Darin Acemoglu and James Robinson have
written a book about why some nations have succeeded in generating sustained
economic growth through industrialisation and others have not, titled "Why
Nations Fail" (Crown Business, New York, 2012). They regard Australia as a
success story.
They focus on the role
of what they describe as "inclusive institutions", which include
democratic accountability and the rule of law. Once they are established, these
institutions create circumstances where the government is accountable and
responsive to citizens, and where the great mass of people can take advantage
of economic opportunities. Acemoglu and Robinson say that these institutions
tend not to emerge in "extractive economies", where the economy is
based on natural resources, and their exploitation is dominated by a narrow
elite. Too often the elite uses its political power to prevent the development
of inclusive institutions which could provide a pathway to industrialisation.
(Ibid).
Argentina is a classic
example. It is a country rich in natural resources, and at the turn of the
twentieth century it was prospering; it was as wealthy at the time as
Australia. But its large landholding elite conceded little to either urban or
rural work forces. It did not industrialise, and remained an extractive economy
and society. It was therefore highly exposed to commodity downturn in the 1930s
and it did not handle the Depression and its aftermath well. Political turmoil
led to military coups in 1943 and again in 1976. From being one of the world's
most affluent nations at the start of the twentieth century, it finished the
century a long way down the chart. In 2001 it defaulted on its debts.
Australia could have
had a similar experience, but we did not. New South Wales was indeed an ideal
location for an extensive pastoral industry based on cheap convict labour. In
the early nineteenth century its political leaders wanted to turn New South
Wales into an extractive economy free of inclusive institutions. Their first
problem was the British Government, which was persuaded to lay the foundation
for a working democracy in the colony of New South Wales.
Their second problem
was Victoria. The Victorian gold rushes of the 1850s led to direct conflict
between the gold diggers and the pastoral landholding class. Victoria got limited
parliamentary democracy, and then small farmers. The Victorian Government also
took up the cause of protection to provide additional employment opportunities
and in order to create a more self-reliant society. Protection was strongly,
but unsuccessfully, opposed by the pastoral elite and their merchant
supporters, and by the end of the nineteenth century, in Victoria, although not
in New South Wales, most leading politicians were committed protectionists.
The Victorian Alfred
Deakin was both a protectionist and a radical social democrat. His
parliamentary group wanted to create an Australia free of the old world class
and caste differences. Deakin was able to implement much of the protectionist
agenda, including its social democrat dimension, between 1905 and 1909 when he
was Prime Minister of a government which ruled with the support of the Labor
Party.
Deakin expressly set
out to make Australia a more diverse and self-reliant industrialised economy.
He and his supporters were worried that Australia could become, in his words of
1905, an economy of "hewers of wood, drawers of water, shearers of wool,
and growers of wheat". (Bob Birrell, "Federation, the Secret
Story", Duffy and Snellgrove, Sydney 2001, p. 203). Furthermore the Deakin
Government linked receipt of tariff protection to the payment of 'fair wages',
establishing the Commonwealth Arbitration Court, which incorporated the
principle of a living wage into its determination of industrial awards.
Australia developed a reputation as a 'working man's paradise'.
Australia was hit hard
by the Depression, but the Australian Settlement and the Federation-era
institutions survived the test. There was little social unrest, and after the
Second World War Australia's manufacturing exports expanded and we enjoyed a
golden age of prosperity.
Between 1946 and 1974
real per capita GDP increased at an average annual rate of 2.2 percent. From
1974 to 1991 it slipped to 1.5 percent, and between 1991 and 2010 it was still
lower than in the post war years, at 2 percent. (Ian McLean, "Why Australia
Prospered", Princeton University Press, 2013, p. 16).
Of course during these
later years the Australian Settlement has been abandoned. Industrialised
countries benefit from the productivity gains that flow from adopting the
latest technology in manufacturing. On the other hand, economies based on
natural resources face diminishing returns. Miners have to dig deeper or
exploit ore bodies with lower mineral content. Farmers have to farm less
productive land, or add more fertiliser or water to their crop. This leads to
lower returns on capital and labour.
But before the
Australian Settlement was abandoned, Australia had a vibrant manufacturing
industry, thriving in such diverse areas as pharmaceuticals, chemicals,
automotive, iron and steel, and telecommunications.
Our pharmaceutical
industry had prospered due to the Labor Government's Factor F scheme. This
piece of industry policy paid drug companies who increased their research and
development, production and exports from Australia. It was successful in increasing
exports of pharmaceuticals from $321 million in 1990-91 to $894 million in
1995-96 and $2.3 billion by 2001-2, jumping by a factor of seven in just over a
decade. Later on the program was cut and in the decade after 2001-2 we built up
a trade deficit in drugs of $6.9 billion. Pharmaceutical company executives
contrast the present situation with the Factor F era. According to the head of
AstraZeneca it manufactures in Australia because the Labor Government
"incentivised pharmaceutical companies to invest in sophisticated
manufacturing facilities in the 1980s". ("Pharmas need to more
drugs", Nigel Bowen, The Age, 19 May 2014).